Minsky proposed theories linking
financial market fragility, in the normal
life cycle of an
economy, with
speculative investment bubbles endogenous to financial markets. Minsky claimed that in
prosperous times, when corporate
cash flow rises beyond what is needed to pay off debt, a
speculative euphoria develops, and soon thereafter debts exceed what borrowers can pay off from their incoming revenues, which in turn produces a
financial crisis. As a result of such speculative borrowing bubbles,
banks and
lenders tighten credit availability, even to companies that can afford
loans, and the
economy subsequently contracts.
This slow movement of the financial system from stability to fragility, followed by crisis, is something for which Minsky is best known, and the phrase "
Minsky moment" refers to this aspect of Minsky's academic work.
"He offered very good insights in the '60s and '70s when linkages between the financial markets and the economy were not as well understood as they are now," said
Henry Kaufman, a Wall Street
money manager and economist. "He showed us that financial markets could move frequently to excess. And he underscored the importance of the
Federal Reserve as a
lender of last resort."
[4]
Minsky's model of the
credit system, which he dubbed the "financial instability hypothesis"
(FIH),
[5] incorporated many ideas already circulated by
John Stuart Mill,
Alfred Marshall,
Knut Wicksell and
Irving Fisher.
[6] "A fundamental characteristic of our economy," Minsky wrote in 1974, "is that the financial system swings between robustness and fragility and these swings are an integral part of the process that generates
business cycles."
[7]
Disagreeing with many mainstream economists of the day, he argued that these swings, and the booms and busts that can accompany them, are inevitable in a so-called free
market economy – unless government steps in to control them, through
regulation,
central bank action and other tools. Such mechanisms did in fact come into existence in response to crises such as the
Panic of 1907 and the
Great Depression. Minsky opposed the
deregulation that characterized the 1980s.
It was at the
University of California, Berkeley that seminars attended by
Bank of America executives helped him to develop his theories about lending and economic activity, views he laid out in two books,
John Maynard Keynes (1975), a classic study of the economist and his contributions, and
Stabilizing an Unstable Economy (1986), and more than a hundred professional articles.
Further developments
Minsky's theories have enjoyed some popularity, but have had little influence in
mainstream economics or in
central bank policy.
Minsky stated his theories verbally, and did not build mathematical models based on them. Consequently, his theories have not been incorporated into mainstream economic models, which do not include private debt as a factor. The post-Keynesian economist
Steve Keen has recently developed models of endogenous economic crises based on Minsky's theories, but they are currently at the research stage and do not enjoy widespread use.
[8]
Minsky's theories, which emphasize the
macroeconomic dangers of
speculative bubbles in asset prices, have also not been incorporated into central bank policy. However, in the wake of the
financial crisis of 2007–2010 there has been increased interest in policy implications of his theories, with some central bankers advocating that central bank policy include a Minsky factor.
[9]
Understanding Minsky's financial instability hypothesis
Hyman Minsky's theories about debt accumulation received revived attention in the media during the
subprime mortgage crisis of the late 2000s.
[10]
Minsky argued that
a key mechanism that pushes an economy towards a crisis is the accumulation of debt by the non-government sector. He identified three types of borrowers that contribute to the accumulation of insolvent debt:
hedge borrowers,
speculative borrowers, and
Ponzi borrowers.
The "hedge borrower" can make debt payments (covering interest and principal) from current cash flows from investments. For the "speculative borrower", the cash flow from investments can service the debt, i.e., cover the interest due, but the borrower must regularly roll over, or re-borrow, the principal. The "Ponzi borrower" (named for
Charles Ponzi, see also
Ponzi scheme) borrows based on the belief that the appreciation of the value of the asset will be sufficient to refinance the debt but could not make sufficient payments on interest or principal with the cash flow from investments; only the appreciating asset value can keep the Ponzi borrower afloat.
If the use of Ponzi finance is general enough in the financial system, then the inevitable disillusionment of the Ponzi borrower can cause the system to seize up: when the bubble pops, i.e., when the asset prices stop increasing, the speculative borrower can no longer refinance (roll over) the principal even if able to cover interest payments. As with a line of
dominoes, collapse of the speculative borrowers can then bring down even hedge borrowers, who are unable to find loans despite the apparent soundness of the underlying investments.
[5]
Applying the hypothesis to the subprime mortgage crisis
Economist
Paul McCulley described how Minsky's hypothesis translates to the
subprime mortgage crisis.
[11] McCulley illustrated the three types of borrowing categories using an analogy from the mortgage market: a hedge borrower would have a traditional
mortgage loan and is paying back both the principal and interest; the speculative borrower would have an
interest-only loan, meaning they are paying back only the interest and must refinance later to pay back the principal; and the ponzi borrower would have a
negative amortization loan, meaning the payments do not cover the interest amount and the principal is actually increasing. Lenders only provided funds to ponzi borrowers due to a belief that housing values would continue to increase.
McCulley writes that the progression through Minsky's three borrowing stages was evident as the credit and housing bubbles built through approximately August 2007. Demand for housing was both a cause and effect of the rapidly-expanding
shadow banking system, which helped fund the shift to more lending of the speculative and ponzi types, through ever-riskier mortgage loans at higher levels of
leverage. This helped drive the housing bubble, as the availability of credit encouraged higher home prices. Since the bubble burst, we are seeing the progression in reverse, as businesses de-leverage, lending standards are raised and the share of borrowers in the three stages shifts back towards the hedge borrower.
McCulley also points out that human nature is inherently pro-cyclical, meaning, in Minsky's words, that "from time to time, capitalist economies exhibit inflations and debt deflations which seem to have the potential to spin out of control. In such processes, the economic system's reactions to a movement of the economy amplify the movement – inflation feeds upon inflation and debt-deflation feeds upon debt deflation." In other words, people are
momentum investors by nature, not
value investors. People naturally take actions that expand the high and low points of cycles. One implication for policymakers and regulators is the implementation of counter-cyclical policies, such as contingent capital requirements for banks that increase during boom periods and are reduced during busts.
en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Hyman_Minsk